Wildlife farms may stifle rise in organised crime poaching

 

By Michael 't Sas Rolfes, 3/24/2010

 

Editorial originally published and reprinted with permission from IPN, International Policy Network

 

  Bans on wildlife trade are counterproductive and contribute to organised crime. It's time for a re-think.


THE UN Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species seeks to curtail that trade but the mood is bleak at the current 15th conference in Doha, Qatar. CITES secretary-general Willem Wijnstekers says attempts to halt the decline of tigers have "failed miserably", while organised crime is increasing its role in illegal trade. It's time to consider alternatives.


Since its inception 35 years ago, CITES has progressively stepped up attempts to control or shut down the trade in parts of tigers, elephants, rhinoceroses and bears, yet demand persists, for both ornamental and "medicinal" uses. Tiger bone, rhino horn and bear gall bladders have been used for thousands of years as traditional treatments in China and many other Asian countries.


In an attempt to meet this demand, people in China and some neighbouring states have tried to breed captive bears, tigers and rhinoceroses. Horrified Western conservation and animal welfare groups have spared no effort in trying to shut them down, but this sentimental response may not be in the best interests of the remaining wild animals.


Bear farming is an established practice in China, which allows a domestic trade in bear bile (extracted from gall bladders while they are alive). It's a nasty business but although illegal trade in bear parts continues in unstable countries such as Burma, there does not appear to be much large-scale poaching of wild bears.


Tiger farming began in China in the 1980s and currently harbours more tigers than are in the wild. However, China banned domestic trade in tiger products in 1993 and the ban remains in place, despite repeated domestic calls to reopen trade. Meanwhile, wild tiger numbers have dropped from about 5000 or more in 1996 to below 3200 today, and there is evidence of organised, large-scale poaching in, for example, India.


Some farmed tiger parts appear to have leaked on to the black market, leading the World Bank and others to call for an end to captive breeding in China - removing what is described as a loophole, and any potential for legal trade once and for all.


But is this a good idea? The evidence suggests that demand for certain wildlife products is not very sensitive to changes in price, so when supply is restricted, price rises dramatically. This is very similar to oil, the price of which rises dramatically in response to small changes in short-term demand, as in 2008.


The ban on wildlife trade generates high rewards for those willing to risk it. Disposable incomes in Asia are rising fast so although tastes may be changing, consumers remain willing to spend more for illegal wildlife products. Even as law enforcers clamp down on loopholes, new ones are exploited, such as using lion bones instead of tiger bones.


Even if all these supplies are cut off, demand looks set to remain high, so the suppliers of last resort will be the serious professionals: organised criminals who specialise in smuggling arms, drugs and other high-value illicit goods. This presents a challenge to conservation for two reasons.


First, experience shows organised crime is usually several steps ahead of the law, especially in lower-income countries, where there is an almost endless supply of corruptible officials and willing suppliers.


Second, unlike opportunists who exploit loopholes in laws and breeding programs, criminal gangs may set their sights on what matters most to biodiversity conservation: the genetically viable core populations in protected areas. This has happened with rhinos and elephants, and more recently with tigers.


Underpaid enforcement officers in protected areas are usually no match for gangs of heavily armed and seriously determined professional poachers.


Attempts to wish away Asian demand for wildlife products through moral suasion, punitive regulation and bans have failed.
The criminalisation of wildlife trade is inexorably driving it into the control of organised crime.


Shutting down China's captive breeding would reinforce the criminal monopoly on trade in tigers by eliminating potential alternative sources. Given the persistent demand for tiger products and rhino horn and the dwindling numbers of wild tigers and rhinos - in spite of decades of trade restrictions - it is time to explore options that would legally satisfy demand, save wild animals and undermine organised crime.

 

Michael 't Sas-Rolfes is an environmental economist based in South Africa and a fellow of International Policy Network.


 

 

 

 

 


www.REXANO.org